Lancaster1966 Lancaster A New Approach to Consumer Theory Author(s): Kelvin J. Lancaster Source: The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 74, No. 2 (Apr., 1966), pp. 132-157 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1828835 Accessed: 22/09/2008 02:58

In the traditional consumer model, the relationship between goods (GOODS) was two choices: same goods or different goods

  • The relationship between butter and margarine is the same as the relationship between shoes and boats
  • Are red Chevrolet and gray Chevrolet the same goods or different goods?

So we built a model in which utility is defined for features rather than goods.

  • Create a new model with the following three elements (p. 134)
    • 1: Utility is a function of characteristic (previously it was a function of goods).
    • 2: A good has one or more characteristics, and a characteristic is shared by several goods.
    • 3: The characteristics of the combination of goods are different from those of the individual goods. image This would allow, for example, a red Chevrolet and a gray Chevrolet to be described as “goods that share most characteristics and differ only in color characteristics.

Representation of the model in the formulas

. In the Simplified model, which will be explained later, there is a one-to-one correspondence between Activity (purchase and other actions) and Good, but this is not the case in the general model, so Good is represented by x and Activity by y. When Activity and Good are in one-to-one correspondence, A is a unit matrix and . A, which expresses this relationship between Activity and Good, is assumed to be linear and objective.

The relationship between Activity y and Characteristic z is assumed to be linear and objective as well.

Utility U is a function of z. In contrast to the conventional model where it is a function of x.

The linear budget constraint is expressed as using the price vector p.

  • (Lancaster intended to use k for later discussion as the level of activity for the purposes of later discussion.)

To sum up. become

In the Simplified Model, where Activity and Good have a one-to-one correspondence, x and y are considered identical. become

In the previous model, utility was defined in Good-space (G-space, the space of goods), so the relationship with the budget constraint could be expressed by Indifference-curve (indifference curve), but in this model, utility is defined in Characteristic -space(C-space, space of features), so a mapping is necessary.

  • p137
    • a) Since convex set on G-space is also convex on C-space, the budget constraint line is also convex on C-space.
    • b) Since there is not necessarily an inverse in B, any z on the C-space does not necessarily have x on the corresponding G-space
    • c) If there is an inverse matrix, this is also a mapping of a convex hull onto a convex hull, so the convexity of U is preserved

the structure of consumption technology

In the Simplified model, A disappears, so B is important. This B is called consumption technology (consumer technology). The discussion is divided into three patterns depending on the shape of this B.

  • 1: If the number of features is the same as the number of goods
    • Some conditions lead back to the conventional model.
  • 2: If the number of features is greater than the number of goods
    • Bx=z, viewed as a simultaneous equation, has no solution in general because “there are more equalities than the number of variables”.
    • So think in slices (ignoring some of too many features).
    • Lancaster emphasizes that convexity is maintained at this time
    • nishio.iconto “what does it mean in the real world that there is no exact solution for x corresponding to given z?” I feel that this is not the case. In the real world, if a consumer is not satisfied with a product on the market that satisfies his/her “desired feature z,” he/she will buy a similar product if it is satisfactory, and thus the consumer will be absorbed into the framework of utility maximization. There is no need for an exact solution.
  • 3: If the number of goods is greater than the number of features
    • At this time, there exists more than one x satisfying Bx=z
    • The customer then makes a choice among those multiple x’s.
      • The EFFICIENCY of that choice is MINIMUM COST (“efficient” in the sense of the efficient market hypothesis is used).
    • The optimization for efficient x* for given z* is
    • The set of z for which px=k is satisfied when z* is moved is called the characteristic frontier
      • This indicates the boundary of the set of features that can be maximally obtained within a given budget constraint

This is the end of the explanation of the model, and now we will apply this model to various problems.

nishio.iconImpressions of

  • The space of goods is finite, which is unavoidable given the computational resources available in 1966.
    • In dealing with contexts such as new product development, there are a myriad of goods because the natural behavior is to “choose the one that seems to have the highest customer utility out of the myriad of products that could be created.
    • (This is not an outlandish idea; recent natural language processing considers the word space to be of infinite dimension, and includes a prior distribution using the Dirichlet process, etc.)
    • Or approximate in a sufficiently large dimensional space.
  • We are dealing with this as a linear problem.
    • I suppose it is inevitable because it would be analytically unsolvable, but since the quantity of goods is a continuous value, it would be possible to act “buy 1/3 3.5” HDD and 2/5 5” HDD” with a limited budget.
    • Realistically, it’s impossible to buy half a camera, and can only be approximated by cloth, water, grain, etc. sold by weight.
    • This is due to the fact that we are treating the choice of goods x as a vector in the first place.
    • If we insert the one-hot constraint “customers buy only one good”, then one point on the C-space will correspond to one point on the G-space.
      • Instead, it will not be able to handle the COMBINATION of goods, but it is better to be clear about what you are good at and what you are not good at.
    • The shattering of G-space makes it difficult to discuss budget constraint lines, but we can add the inverse of price as one of the features, as Adner 2002 does
      • Instead, the discussion of technology constraint lines on C-space carries more weight.

This page is auto-translated from [/nishio/A New Approach to Consumer Theory](https://scrapbox.io/nishio/A New Approach to Consumer Theory) using DeepL. If you looks something interesting but the auto-translated English is not good enough to understand it, feel free to let me know at @nishio_en. I’m very happy to spread my thought to non-Japanese readers.